Polaris Capital Management
  • HOME
  • INVESTMENT APPROACH
  • TEAM
  • CONTACT
  • BLOG

Another look at Ergodicity Economics

5/22/2021

1 Comment

 
​I came across a lecture notes on Ergodicity Economics: https://ergodicityeconomics.files.wordpress.com/2018/06/ergodicity_economics.pdf. It looks like the whole theory goes far beyond the article in the Nature Physics, we discussed in the previous post. Interestingly, Ole Peters applies his theory to find an optimal leverage which defines the portfolio with the highest time average growth rate. According to his calculations it is equal to:
Picture
We thought it might be a good idea to backtest a strategy on S&P 500 Total Return Index to see if the optimal leverage improves portfolio performance. An idea of a non-constant leverage to boost an investment performance is not a new one. There are multiple investment products such as Constant Proportion Portfolio Insurance (CPPI) products and volatility targeting funds. Those products are based upon different portfolio construction principles compare to the ones specified in ergodicity economics theory. 

Unfortunately, the author does not specify the way he estimates an excess return of risky assets, which is µ and volatility of risky assets, which is σ in equation (316).  
To estimate volatility we use an industry wide approach and calculate historical volatility for the last 500 trading days. For stock market returns, it is more tricky. There is no industry wide standard model to project future expected returns. We use three different indicators to project five-year returns: P/E ratio, Tobin’s Q and the Household Equity Share. P/E ratio and Tobin’s Q are well known measures used in valuations of companies, whereas the Household Equity Share is a relatively new predictor. It was introduced by Yang and Zhang in their paper: https://cba.lmu.edu/media/lmucollegeofbusinessadministration/responsivesite/research/Yang_Household%20equity%20share.pdf
The Household Equity Share represents retail investor positioning and according to Yang and Zhang it outperforms popular forecasters of market returns such as the cyclically adjusted price-earnings ratio, the equity share in new issuances, the consumption-wealth ratio, the term spread, and the Treasury bill yield. 
​
To get an expected return on a five-year horizon we simply regress on a quarterly basis five-year rolling returns on our three indicators. i.e. to avoid forward data contamination we iteratively add an additional quarter of observation when it becomes available. The choice of a five-year horizon is somewhat arbitrary. Since we perform regressions on levels, we have an issue of nonstationary of our variables. Therefore, before we run regressions, we need to make sure that our indicators cointegrate with rolling returns.  We have stronger cointegrating relationships between our indicators and five-year returns than between our indicators and ten-year returns. For that reason, a preference was made in favour of five-year return signals. The results of our historical back test are on the figure below. We assumed a zero bid/ask spread for a portfolio rebalancing and our funding rate is 3 month LIBOR. We further assumed, in line with what was described in the article, that in the case of a negative expected returns positions in the market are closed and all funds are allocated to cash, which also pays 3 month LIBOR.


Picture
Source: Bloomberg, http://www.econ.yale.edu//~shiller/data.htm
​In terms of an absolute performance of different indicators the results are drastically different. A portfolio which uses P/E ratio as a signal (represented by green line and right axis) significantly outperforms a portfolio based on Tobin’s Q and the one based on Household Equity Shares indicators. On the other hand, this portfolio has the sharpest (80%) drawdown. On a risk-adjusted basis, the performance of all portfolios is identical: the Sharpe ratio for all three portfolios is around 0.5. 

How does that compare with the performance of a very naïve strategy that goes 100% long if expected return is positive and stays in cash when expected performance is negative?  The results are on a figure below:


Picture
Source: Bloomberg, http://www.econ.yale.edu//~shiller/data.htm
Although, this chart looks different compare to a previous one the risk-adjusted basis a performance of the naïve Long/Flat strategies is almost identical to the performance of portfolios with the leverage derived from ergodicity economics theory. 
One can obviously argue that the indicators we used are not the perfect ones and one can perform much better if indicators were more precise. For that, reason we decided to test a performance of the optimal leverage strategy where long term return is known in advance. Specifically, we use 8% as a yearly expected total return rate which is roughly the rate of return of S&P 500 Total Return Index for the last 30 years. The results are on a figure below:
Picture
 Source: Bloomberg
The portfolio had more than 90% drawdown and it took almost 20 years to get back to the High Water Mark. The Sharpe ratio for the strategy is 0.46. Both Sharpe ratio and drawdowns for this strategy are inferior to the Sharpe ratios and drawdowns for the strategies that used Tobin’s Q, P/E ratio and Household Equity Shares as indicators.
Curiously, upon further reading it appears that the author argues that an optimal leverage should always be equal to 1!

Picture
In our view, this statement is not entirely consistent with equation (316) and even more importantly, it contradicts to the volatility scaling technique, which is a founding block of modern risk management approach both on a buy-side and on a sale-side. To get things into perspective it would make sense to look at the performance on the Nikkei index on the figure below:
Picture
Despite negative interest rates, Abenomics and multiple rounds of quantitative easing the index today is almost 30% lower than it was back in 1989! 
​
To conclude, we found very little evidence that ergodicity economics gives results consistent with the empirical market data. The optimal leverage recommended by the theory does not give much of an added value. It does not improve risk-adjusted return and significantly increases risk of potential drawdowns. 


​
1 Comment

A Practitioner's take on Ergodicity Economics

5/9/2021

0 Comments

 
In a recently published article (The ergodicity problem in economics | Nature Physics), Ole Peters introduces a novel approach of looking at century-old problems of decision-making under uncertainty. Peters highlights a difference between time average and ensemble average.  He argues that time ensemble average is a poor measure for non-ergodic processes of assessments of future payoff/investment returns. By carefully addressing the question of ergodicity, the article attempts to resolve many puzzles besetting the current economic formalism in a natural and empirically testable way.

The author proposes to maximize expected growth rate, where growth rate is ergodic variable. He estimates that playing with an entire fortune a game described in the equation (2) of the original paper not an optimal investment decision.
Picture
This game/investment provides investors a negative rate of growth when carried out in a multiplicative format. Therefore, the author argues, one should not accept a bet described in the equation (2) on the entire wealth. That confirms market wisdom:  playing a game with a significant probability to lose practically all one’s wealth is never a good idea for a rational investor.

Ole Peters’s approach provides readers an interesting framework to analyse different investment opportunities and benefits of diversification between different strategies.

While playing a game described in (2) with one’s whole fortune does not make good sense, it does stand to reason to allocate part of a portfolio to uncorrelated strategies with the payoff described in (2). This will provide an investment return with lesser volatility.

Hedge funds and high frequency traders operate in this fashion. It is arguably difficult to find a standalone scalable strategy with a high Sharpe ratio, but it is possible to construct a portfolio with relatively high Sharpe ratios from standalone strategies carrying low Sharpe ratios.

The table below put this into perspective. It shows risk-return characteristics for game (2) and S&P 500 total return index over the last 30 years.
Picture
The game (2) displays attractive risk/return characteristics compared to the stock market.

It would be difficult to argue that people should abstain from investing in risky assets. Those who have not invested a part of their wealth and remained long cash, have typically regretted these decisions later on.

This leads to the conclusion that it does make sense to play the game (2) with proper risk scaling and portfolio diversification.

Ergodicity theory confirms this logic: a strategy with 90%/10% allocation has a positive rate of growth and is therefore a preferable choice compared to the alternative of remaining 100% in cash. The theory tells us interestingly that an optimal investment is game (2) is 25% of the fortune.

All in all, ergodicity theory confirms the benefits of portfolio diversification which was first proposed by Harry Markowitz[i].

One glaring question is: Will diversification help on the downside? Today risky assets are driven by one main factor: excess liquidity provision by Central Banks. The question is valid but it’s outside of the scope of this discussion.

When it comes down to a choice of an optimal strategy under uncertainty we are less convinced that an optimization of growth rate, which is an ergodic process,  indeed provides a best possible solution among all alternatives.
In certain cases, it gives the results well in line with empirical observations (see above), but in others, the results are less convincing. A multiplicative growth process, for example, gives results, which are not necessarily consistent with investors’ preferences.

Specifically, according to the ergodic theory, an investor should prefer playing a game making 1% on a daily basis but losing 99.9% twice a year instead of playing a game as described in equation (2).  It also says that, instead of staying in cash, an investor should play a game where she gets daily return of 1% but once every three years she loses 99.9% of her wealth in one day.

It is not certain that individual investors will reveal preferences in line with the predictions of ergodic theory. There are many option underwriting strategies and negative gamma programs, which indeed deliver superior returns at the risk of a 90% loss of capital. However, strategies, which lead to these loss percentages, are not recommended for retail investors.

It might be a different story for institutional investors though. The concept of “skin in the game[ii]” for some of these investors is a foreign concept, and many might happily accept such a huge tail risk playing with investors’ money instead of their own.

The author makes another bold statement claiming that the whole idea of utility function maximization is an error in the foundation of economics. Peters writes that people are not all that different, and the only thing which differentiates people are circumstances i.e., wealth.

Wealthy people subsequently maximizing their growth via an additive process would appear to be brave, whereas less well-to-do people maximizing their wealth via a multiplicative process would appear to be scared.

There are no doubts that wealth is one of the key components in both portfolio allocation and investment analysis, but it is only one of several parameters as shown by different portfolio allocations for investors similar wealth and consumption buckets. Human nature means that people are prone behave spontaneously and irrationally based upon hopes, fears, and beliefs.

Downside risk can be assessed differently by different people within the same wealth bracket. An anecdotal, and somewhat sad example can be drawn from the people’s preferences during the process of the so-called “Russian privatization” of the 1990s. During this period certain people were willing to accept a game with rather drastic extremes:

    a 90% probability of centupling their wealth and
    a 10% of ending up on in the graveyard.

Moreover, they played multiple rounds of this game. Some of the winners are known to us now as the “Russian oligarchs”. The second group remains silent and unknown.

One can argue that probabilities, and perception of probabilities, in this game were different for different people. While certainly true, it does not change the fact that some people in the same wealth bracket were willing to play the game with infinite downside while others were not.

On balance, it seems that ergodicity economics is definitely an interesting concept, which explains certain aspects of investors’ behaviour. The results of these predictions do not necessarily fall in line with empirical observations in certain cases. 
​
Yet, the same can be also said about many models- not just in Economics. A less dismal science, such as Physics, can provide a fine example.  Space satellite engineering and construction use principles of Lagrangian formalisms and application of Newton’s laws. However, applying the same principles to construction of a nuclear reactor will lead to catastrophic failure. 
Therefore, it should be acknowledged that models in ergodicity economics, like many other models, do carry certain limitations.
 


[i] Harry Markowitz. Portfolio Selection. The Journal of Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1. (Mar., 1952), pp. 77-91.

[ii] Nassim Nicholas Taleb  Skin in the Game: Hidden Asymmetries in Daily Life (2018)
0 Comments

    Author

    Alexey Yeremenko, PhD

    Archives

    May 2021
    September 2019

    Categories

    All
    Ergodicity Economics
    Monetary Policy

    RSS Feed

  ©2024 Polaris Capital Management Sarl

The material contained in this web site does not constitute an offer for sale. This communication is not intended as and is not to be taken as an offer or solicitation with respect to the purchase or sale of any security or interest, nor does it constitute an offer or solicitation in any jurisdiction, including those in which such an offer or solicitation is not authorised or to any person to whom it is unlawful to make such a solicitation or offer. Past performance is not an indication of future performance.